This
article is written together with Eduardo Giménez, Professor of Economics at the
University of Vigo. It is the first part out of four, which will be published
in this blog. The full article will be published in the book
"Automatization" , which will be published by the European Liberal
Forum at the end of the year.
Offshoring
The development of
information and communications technologies has resulted in a drastic reduction
in both costs of processing information and transmitting it between two any
point on the globe. The production processes do not necessarily have to be
organized locally any more. Now, the possibility of vertical integration is
opened at a planetary scale. This means that the various tasks of a production
process can be located in distant parts of the globe. This process is known as
offshoring.
Of course, this process of offshoring
has a significant impact on international trade. In particular, trade in
intermediate products is gradually becoming increasingly important relative to traditional
trade in final products; much of the recent surge of international trade comes
from middle- and low-countries; and prices of manufactured imports by developed
countries from developing countries are dramatically declining. Baldwin (2011)
argues that we are witnessing since the late eighties to a second type of
globalization characterized by what he called connective technologies, which
are enabling a drastic reduction in the cost of transmitting information (thus
facilitating access to knowledge and global connection of people and
companies), while the previous stage of globalization was driven by a sharp
reduction in transport costs and political barriers to trade.
Figure 1
Source: Baldwin (2011). |
As Blinder and Krueger
(2013) have argued, essentially any job that does not need to be done in person
(i.e., face-to-face) can ultimately be offshored, regardless of whether its
primary tasks are abstract, routine, or manual. With this possibility in mind,
it is not surprising that offshoring –being possible thank to the information
and communications technologies- is affecting differently to the three
characters of our story. The doctor and the maid perform tasks that cannot be offshored,
not yet at least, while the tasks of the clerk are increasingly being offshored.
Therefore, offshoring is also contributing to alter the relative demand of the
different kinds of workers and, consequently, is affecting their relative
wages.
Occupations threatened by
the computer replacement and those under the threat of relocation are not
exactly the same. However, in general, it can be asserted that many occupations
performed by middle-skill workers –workers with high-school or some college education-
are currently confronting both threats. Autor and Acemoglu (2011) report that
(i) offshorability is highest in clerical and sales occupations which imply a
high degree of routine tasks; (ii) offshorability is also high in professional,
managerial and technical occupations, which imply a high degree of non-routine
tasks, and (iii offshorability is relatively low in production and operative
occupations and even lower in service occupations. The measures of offshorability reported by Acemoglu and Autor are roughly consistent with the measures reported by Blinder and Krueger (2013). However, it must be pointed out that there is a large heterogenity into the category "production and operative occupations". According to the estimates provided by Blinder and Krueger (2013), farming, fishing and forestry occupations, construction and extraction occupations, installation, maintenance and repair occupations, and transporting and material moving occupations have a very low degree of offshorability, but other production occupations have a very high degree of offshorability. In particular, according to their best measure, 80% of jobs in other production occupations are offshorable. Offshorability is also very high in office and administrative support occupations, 41% of job in these occupations are offshorables according to the best measure reported by Blinder and Krueger. Offshorability is also high in sales and related occupations (17.8%), professional and related occupations (20.5%), and managment, business, and financial occupations (16.4%). However, the percentage of offshorable jobs in service occupation is only 0.7%. Blinder and Krueger (2013) estimate that roughly 25% of U.S jobs are offshorable. The fith column of Table 1 displays a measure of offshorability of several occupations in 16 European countries elaborated by Goos et al. (2010) (a higher number means higher offshorability).
Autor, Dorn and Hanson (2015) reports that the U.S. local labor markets whose initial industry composition exposes them to rising Chinese import competition experience significant falls in employment, particularly in manufacturing and among non-college workers. Ebenstein et al. (2009) present evidence that globalization has put downward pressure on worker wages through the reallocation of workers away from higher wage manufacturing jobs into other sectors and other occupations. Using a panel of workers, they find that occupation switching due to trade led to real wage losses of 12 to 17 percentage points.
Table 1
Source: Goos, Maning and Salomons (2010) |
Autor, Dorn and Hanson (2015) reports that the U.S. local labor markets whose initial industry composition exposes them to rising Chinese import competition experience significant falls in employment, particularly in manufacturing and among non-college workers. Ebenstein et al. (2009) present evidence that globalization has put downward pressure on worker wages through the reallocation of workers away from higher wage manufacturing jobs into other sectors and other occupations. Using a panel of workers, they find that occupation switching due to trade led to real wage losses of 12 to 17 percentage points.
Superstars
So far, our history has been
about ordinary workers. Maids, clerks, doctors,...we can find thousands.
However, a small number of workers are out of the norm. They are superstars (see
Rosen (1981)), as the soccer players Leo Messi or Slatan Ibrahimovic. In recent
decades, there has been an impressive burst of earnings of this so-special type
of workers.
The income share of the top
1% of income distribution has soared since the late eighties (see Figure 2). At this stage of
XXI century in countries like the United States or Britain, the top 1% income
share is hovering at the figures observed at the beginning of the past century
(see Atkinson, Piketty and Saez (2011)). In fact, much of the increase in
inequality in income distribution in many developed countries is explained by
the increase in the top 1% (see Bell and Van Reenen (2010)). Keep in mind the
shocking remunerations for the most CEOs of large companies (see Figure 3). Before the
eighties, their earnings were certainly enviable, but did not reach, not even
by far, the stratospheric current figures (see Frydman and Jenter (2010)).
Gabaix and Landier (2006) give an explanation of the increase in CEO earnings
based on the ideas developed below.
Figure 2
Source: Van Reenen (2010). Top 1% share of all income in English speaking countries. |
Figure 3
To understand the relationship between the earnings of the superstars and technical change, consider Luis Suárez, footballer of F.C. Barcelona in the fifties, and Luis Suárez, currently footballer of F.C. Barcelona.[1] In the fifties and sixties, Suárez I, as Suárez II today, produced non-rival goods –shots, dribbling, passing, goals,...- which could be enjoyed by a lot of people at the same time. People paid to see the exploits of Suárez I on the pitch, and now pay for Suárez II’s goals. Suárez I, as Suárez II today, earned a lot of money because a lot of people watched and admired his gaming. However, in the fifties, when Suárez I played soccer, technology only allowed a hundred thousand people to watch Suárez I’s gaming: those people who attended every Sunday to Camp Nou Stadium. Nowadays, millions of people around the globe watch the goals of Suárez II every week on their televisions and millions more may dream of being Suárez II playing on their gaming consoles. More people can currently enjoy Suárez II’s gaming than Suárez I’s in the fifties and sixties thanks to the information and communications technologies. Accordingly, Suárez II’s earnings are much higher than Suárez I ever dreamed.
Moreover, the difference
between Suárez II’s earnings and most players in the Spanish soccer league is
greater than the difference between Súarez I’s earnings and most players in the
Spanish league at those days. In the fifties, football-mad people of Vigo had
to attend Balaídos Stadium to watch R.C. Celta de Vigo matches because they could
not see to play Suárez I every week. They paid their tickets, as the supporters
of F.C Barcelona did to attend Camp Nou Stadium. In the fifties, Barcelona
soccer players earned more money than Celta soccer players because more people
went to watch them, but, not much more. Nowadays, people from Vigo do not need
to attend Balaídos Stadium to watch soccer. They can watch F.C. Barcelona matches
using the pay-perview digital television services and, consequently, Barcelona
soccer players earn much more money than their colleagues of R. C. Celta. This
increase in earning differences is a consequence from that, when people produce
non-rival goods, the winner takes all. In the example, watching soccer in the
stadium is not the same as watching soccer on TV, watching your team is not the
same as watching any other team,…There are several reasons because R.C. Celta
and F.C Barcelona are not perfect substitutes, so that the core idea “winner
takes all” does not work perfectly.
In short, the development of
the information and communications technologies is increasing the degree of
non-rivalry of some goods produced by some economic agents, which allows them
to earn a lot of money if they are the winners of a “winner-take-all” race. This
means that globalization driven by the information and communications
technologies has played an important role in boosting demand for the services
of some superstar workers, which has increased their earnings and income inequality.
References
Acemoglu, D., & Autor,
D. H. (2011). Skills, tasks
and technologies: Implications for employment and earnings. Handbook of Labor Economics, 4,
1043-1171.
Atkinson, A. B., Piketty,
T., & Saez, E. (2011). Top incomes in the long run of History. Journal of Economic Literature, 49(1),
3-71.
Autor, D. H., Dorn, D.,
& Hanson, G. H. (2015). Untangling trade and technology: Evidence from
local labour markets. The Economic
Journal, 125(584), 621-646.
Baldwin, R. (2011). Trade
and industrialisation after globalisation's 2nd unbundling: How building and
joining a supply chain are different and why it matters. NBER Working Paper 17716.
Bell, B., & Van Reenen,
J. (2010). Bankers’ bonuses and extreme wage inequality in the UK. Centre for Economic Performance Special
Report Nº 21.
Blinder, A., & Krueger,
A. B. (2013). Measuring offshorability: A survey approach. Journal of Labor Economics, 31(S1), S97-S128.
Ebenstein, A., Harrison, A., McMillan, M. and S. Phillips (2009). Estimating the impact of trade and ofshoring on American workers using the current populations surveys. NBER Working Paper 15107.
Frydman, C., & Jenter, D. (2010). CEO Compensation. Annual Review of Financial Economics, 2(1), 75-102.
Ebenstein, A., Harrison, A., McMillan, M. and S. Phillips (2009). Estimating the impact of trade and ofshoring on American workers using the current populations surveys. NBER Working Paper 15107.
Frydman, C., & Jenter, D. (2010). CEO Compensation. Annual Review of Financial Economics, 2(1), 75-102.
Gabaix, X. and Landier, A.
(2006). Why has CEO pay increased so much? NBER
Working Paper 12365.
Goos, M., Manning, A., & Salomons, A. (2010). Explaining job polarization in Europe: the roles of technology, globalization and institutions. CEP Discussion Paper Nº 1026, LSE.
Rosen, S. (1981). The
economics of superstars. The American
Economic Review, 71(5), 845-858.
Van Reenen, J. (2011). Wage inequality, technology and trade: 21st century evidence. Labour Economics, 18(6), 730-741.
Van Reenen, J. (2011). Wage inequality, technology and trade: 21st century evidence. Labour Economics, 18(6), 730-741.
[1]
The supporters of Deportivo de La Coruña -hometown of Suarez- had the
opportunity to enjoy the Suárez’s gaming prior to his passage by F.C.
Barcelona. Afterward, Luis Suárez won two European Cups with Inter of Milan. Luis
Suarez is the only Spanish soccer player (Galician, more precisely) winning a
Golden Ball. The homonymous Uruguayan player who currently plays in the ranks
of F.C Barcelona was so named in his honor.
No hay comentarios:
Publicar un comentario